Ages
From the "stone age" to the "space age" --
they used to happen one at a time. Right now, we seem to be going through
several "ages" all at once.
Some folks call this the "jet age," thanks
to all those black-nosed, bent-wing, silver-bellied kerosene-suckers in
the sky. Whatever happened to the "train age"?
Others might still say we're living in the
"atomic age." If the term is falling into disuse, it's probably because
people don't enjoy being reminded of the hazards associated with this once-promising
technology.
From time to time you hear references to the
"television age" or the "computer age." So. there are plenty of ages to
choose from.
The "petroleum age" deserves special consideration.
It's coming to an end. Not surprising. though. Nobody said it would last
forever.
Anybody for the "bicycle age?"
Gold
You can buy between seven and fourteen barrels
of crude oil for an ounce of gold.
Fluctuations have stayed in that range since
the middle sixties. The prices of gold and petroleum are both trending
generally upward, as the value of the currencies you buy them with are
trending downward. But gold and petroleum don't maintain perfect synchrony.
Many economists look at the relative price
data and see confirmation of the conventional wisdom that predatory petroleum
pricing is a cause of inflation. Others glimpse movements in gold prices
occasionally happening earlier than changes in petroleum prices and conclude
that the high price of oil is an effect of inflation. It seems doubtful
that both are correct.
Each interpretation may result from post
hoc ergo propter hoc fallacy. Expressed colloquially: "Event B follows
event A, therefore B was caused by A." Ambiguities in the time relationships
between the As and the Bs permit opposite conclusions by economists. The
real cause of both A and B may be C, something else entirely.
Economists and others need to be reminded of
a cardinal principle of science; a correlation between two observed events
is a necessary -- but not sufficient -- condition to establish a causal
relationship. It is always incumbent upon the framer of an hypothesis to
supply the unifying account, that chain of closely-reasoned, proximate
arguments that connect the events together -- or to a common cause.
A plausible starting point for the case at
hand, is the fact that both commodities, petroleum and gold, are in their
separate ways destined to be used up. the former through combustion, the
latter from being hoarded unusably away.
Meanwhile, you can buy two or three mighty
fine bicycles for an ounce of gold.
Expert
There was a war going on. Not a moral equivalent,
not a police action -- one of those big, good wars we used to declare.
And then win. To help us do that, we had efficiency experts. Any idea where
they all went?
Efficiency experts used to be found in defense
plants with clip-boards and stop-watches measuring things and writing reports
on productivity and such. While Rosie the Riveter was riveting some efficiency
experts stood around and counted the rivets. That may be how efficiency
experts got a reputation for not seeming to do anything. During that war.
God was somebody's co-pilot, but not one efficiency expert made tail gunner
-- or even made tail guns, from all appearances. They made percentages.
"Efficiency experts are expected to talk percentages,"
must have been the advice of a few zealots in their ranks. "How else can
improvements be measured and wars won?"
Though their numerical machinations may have
given some efficiency experts a bad name, there are still plenty of them
around. Only their titles are new. Some of them, no doubt, are still doing
time-and-motion studies, but now they call themselves industrial engineers.
Others broke into the "O.R. Game" -- that's operations research -- and
today many are known as management consultants.
Their modern-day counterparts did well for
themselves. You'll find them in the management of our corporations, in
our legislative bodies -- even among our presidents and prime ministers.
Efficiency experts nowadays make promises to
the effect that there will never be a need to change the way we live --
our life style. Americans won't ever have to give up driving around in
fossil-thirsty vehicles, for example.
"All we have to do is get rid of waste," you'll
hear them say. "Our energy needs can be more than satisfied from known
supplies."
You should be alert for overly optimistic projections
for what "efficiency" gains can achieve. As we approach the end of the
petroleum age, it may be the unhappy duty of bicyclists to disabuse people
of some myths. Out of the current crop of efficiency experts, few seem
to understand the principles.
Here's a crash course you can give them.
To become a real expert in the efficiency field,
you must first understand something about a "process." All your life. you've
been surrounded by processes -- feeding, learning, working, cooking, transporting.
Any process involves putting something in: materials, time, effort -- and
always energy. Any process also involves getting something out -- products,
knowledge, entertainment, noise.
Not all of what one gets out of a process is
desired. Processes also put out waste. The idea, of course, is to minimize
waste. In other words, your job is to maximize what you want to get out
of a process for a given amount of resources put in. That's efficiency.
But you're not an expert yet.
Efficiency is commonly expressed as a percent.
Thus, if one says that a process is 75% efficient, that means one will
get about 75 units of desired output for every 100 units of input, there
being some 25 units given off as waste.
You'll notice right away that a process having
an efficiency greater than 100% is impossible. There must always be some
waste. The second law of thermodynamics even goes so far as to set rigid
upper limits on efficiency, usually far short of 100%.
For any given process, there's only so far
that efficiency improvements can go. Beyond that, you're talking about
entirely different processes.
Bicycles in place of automobiles -- as absurd
and unsettling as that may seem.
Mentalities
Many of our decision-makers and their constituencies
grew up with television. We might well find important clues for understanding
some of the observed mentalities that surround us by reviewing those early
influences.
To what extent did "Have Gun, Will Travel"
influence our decisions in Southeast Asia?
Are past devotees of "0zzie and Harriet"
now responsible for the prime rate?
Does anyone suspect that "Father Knows Best"
helped shape today's nuclear weapons policy?
Shows featuring a talking horse or a flying
nun did little to foster informed skepticism. Others are likely to have
created unrealistic expectations.
Take for example the "Beverly Hillbillies."
You may recall that the opening of each week's episode contained a musical
reprise of how a certain backwoods family came to become overnight millionaires.
The patriarch of the family, according to the song, was out hunting 'possum,
fired his rifle and missed. Where the buckshot struck the ground, "out
flowed bubbling crude."
Off went the whole television audience to
rejoin the transplanted, nouveau riche family in their palatial Beverly
Hills home for that week's comedic variant of culture shock.
Right after a word from our sponsor.
How many people today harbor a fantasy of
some huge reserve of oil lying around just beneath the surface waiting
for an accidental puncture? According to this Beverly Hillbillies mentality,
gasoline should be plentiful and cheap. Why, if it weren't for the villainous
oil companies and their greedy stockholders, we could all go on driving
big cars indefinitely.
Whatever became of "I Dream of Genie?"
Full Price
No process can be 100% efficient. You don't
have to be an efficiency expert to know that. There must always be some
waste.
What happens, though, when you take a waste
product from one process into another where it gets converted into something
useful? Doesn't that make the second process about 100% efficient? In a
way it does.
There are many examples. The heater in your
car uses waste heat from your engine to warm the passenger compartment.
It takes nary an inch-per-gallon from your mileage. You can't beat that
for energy efficiency. Not so with your air conditioner.
The electrical appliances in your home all
give off waste heat: lightbulb and toaster, dishwasher and hair dryer,
television and refrigerator. In winter, that waste heat helps warm the
house, thus reducing the thermal load on your central heating system. Those
appliances, loosely speaking, are 100% energy efficient. Not so in summer,
when each increases the thermal load on your air conditioning system.
There is a catch in the economics. A hair dryer
is a pretty expensive way to heat your home. A kilowatt-hour costs more
than its equivalent in stuff that burns. (Electrical energy is, by the
way, "superior" to heat energy, according to the hierarchy imposed by the
second law of thermodynamics.) So apparently you can have energy efficiency
in a process that is economically inefficient.
You can also have the opposite; an economically
efficient process that is energy inefficient. Energy policy in the U.S.
has traditionally made this a common occurrence. Simply stated, the policy
from the beginning has said, "keep energy cheap." Price controls on energy,
as intended, do stimulate economic development, but by disregarding the
law of supply and demand -- not to mention the second law of thermodynamics
-- price controls also create artificial economic efficiency and foster
energy inefficiency.
We have yet to pay the full price for our energy.
Particularly fossil energy. When we get around to doing so, you can bet
we'll search out the most energy efficient processes we can find.
Even if it means bicycling.
Salvation
Petroleum has been called the Noble Substance.
Considering its many uses, there's probably no more valuable resource on
earth.
We have treated petroleum as an income resource
instead of what it really is, a capital resource.
For example, when Americans urge the petroleum
industry to "produce" more, what we're actually saying is let's invade
capital faster -- a policy which from the beginning had a predictable outcome.
It's troubling to see economists, industrialists, and statesmen ignore
this most obvious fundament of the future.
Any meaningful caution has long ago been displaced
by mindless expectations for technological salvation.
Meanwhile, the global quest for a direct replacement
for the Noble Substance has turned up nothing. Except for the bicycle,
all of the identified "alternatives" so far have serious economic drawbacks
or seemingly insurmountable environmental defects.
Bicyclists might take the lead in finding hope
for the future based on voluntary adaptation to realities, not on wishful
thinking.
Guzzling
A gallon guzzled back in the '60s was the same
as a gallon guzzled in the '70s. Only we didn't give it much thought.
A gallon saved in the '80s is the same as a
gallon saved in the '90s. Give that some thought next time you pass a bicyclist.
Please.
Manageability
How many naugs did they kill to cover that
car seat?
That's no longer a joke. Everybody knows that
naugahyde is a petroleum product.
Using petroleum for a synthetic fabric does
seem more enduring than burning it up in an engine. It's still a non-replenishable
natural resource, however. An even better idea is to use animal skins.
The issue is manageability.
Mankind can manage the perpetual availability
of any animal on earth: the cow, the caribou, the gray whale, the baby
seal. Whether we will -- by establishing and enforcing international policies
to do so -- is a question. But we can.
Not so with petroleum. It is not "manageable."
Nothing we can do will guarantee an unending supply.
The naug is not an endangered species. It is
doomed.
One-Way Street
Economics, we're told, is a science.
As such, it can reasonably be expected to invoke
canons of evidence and proposition -- rather than opinion. Yet, there are
those who say that if you take ten economists and lay them end-to-end,
they'd all point in different directions. Detractors scoff at the lack
of precision in economics, calling it the "one-digit science."
Whether these criticisms are fair or not, when
it comes to dealing with non-replenishable natural resources, economic
theory encounters some withering limitations.
Economics has to do with the production, distribution,
and consumption of things. Studying its theories and projections gives
one a sense of, well, flowing -- the flowing of raw materials, goods, services,
capital, wealth. There are cycles -- plenty of backing and filling, like
waves on the beach. And you find economic tides, too.
Measurements tend to be represented as incremental
and decremental changes. Productivity went up by such-and-such; housing-starts
by so-and-so; cost-of-living by umpty-ump. Sometimes the base figures quietly
lose their meaning, except for the purpose of comparing corresponding figures
for different times and places, different industries and political regimes.
Does anybody really know what to do with an absolute value of "gross national
product per capita" other than to subtract it from, or divide it by, another
one?
Energy is a unique commodity.
Energy is essential for everything else --
for the mining, growing, harvesting, processing -- and even the recycling
of any other commodity. You need a ton of coal to make a ton of steel --
whether from scrap or from ore. Energy itself cannot be recycled.
Energy is on a one-way street -- toward outer
space.
In all its forms, energy originated in the
sun a long time ago, or in the formation of the earth, even a longer time
ago. Living things, including people, harness and then release energy from
various sources.
The most desirable energy is that highly-concentrated,
geological stuff we call fossils -- the very best being petroleum. Once
mined and combusted, fossils are gone forever, their last remnants of heat
simply radiated away "toward unimagined voids beyond the sky."
While fossil-derived energy flows through our
various economic systems, it gets treated by conventional economic theory
like any other gradually changing variable. Instead, on the scale of history,
fossil energy is an utterly transient thing.
So, how can economics assign an absolute geological
value to an irreplaceable, essential commodity -- that's running out?
INURENCE
"Did
you ever feel a stone in your shoe?"
"Uh
huh."
"Did
you ever walk around for awhile with a stone in your shoe and get kind-a
used to it?"
"Yeah.
So?"
"Did
you ever walk around for awhile with a stone in your shoe, get use to it,
and take it out?"
"For
sure."
"Did
you ever walk around for awhile with a stone in your shoe, get used to
it, take it out, and then miss it for the rest of the day?"
"Where
are we going with this?"
"Funny,
isn't it, how we adapt to life's irritations: a snoring mate, a sticking
drawer, a rattling kickstand, a smelly car?"
"Yep,
funny."
"Did
you ever walk around for awhile with a stone in your shoe, get used to
it, take it out, miss it, and later feel a stone -- in your other shoe?"
"Nope."
Currency
Economic theory models the world as a network
of entities transacting with one another. In each transaction, you have
goods or services flowing in one direction and money flowing in the opposite
direction. One kind of goods is energy.
Actually, all kinds of goods are energies,
directly or indirectly. The same is true for all kinds of services.
Raw materials, from aluminum to zinc, cannot
be mined or refined; work-in-process cannot be shaped, assembled, or packaged;
finished products cannot be distributed -- without the expenditure of energy.
Farms and feedlots, dairies and hatcheries all need energy to operate.
So do hospitals, schools, banks, cafeterias, or wherever people expend
human effort for other people. Even supplying energy needs a supply of
energy.
So energy might be considered the "universal
transactant," a ubiquitous counter-currency embodied within all other things,
swimming against the world's monetary streams. |